Book: p. 26.
Earth economics studies the economy of our planet from the perspective of an autarkic system (a “closed economy”). It ignores the constituent national and regional parts of the planet economy and focuses on the whole. The book respects the heritages of IS/LM (Keynes) and neoclassical growth (Solow) not out of economic respect but because these tools are very useful in understanding the crisis and the policy response to that crisis.
Thursday, September 12, 2013
Growth update
Book: p. 26.
Saturday, July 6, 2013
Fight the middle income trap
How to Avoid Middle-Income Traps? Evidence from Malaysia
Authors:
Aaron Flaaen, Ejaz Ghani, and Saurabh Mishra
Malaysia’s
structural transformation from low to middle income has made it one of the most
prominent manufacturing exporters in the world. However, in the
competitive global economy, like many other middle-income economies, it is sandwiched
between low-wage economies on one side and more innovative advanced economies
on the other. What can Malaysia do? Does Malaysia need a new growth
strategy
To read more: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTPREMNET/Resources/EP120.pdf
Book: p. 135.
To read more: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTPREMNET/Resources/EP120.pdf
Book: p. 135.
Wednesday, June 19, 2013
Growth on a Finite Planet: Resources, Technology, and Population in the Long Run
We study the interactions between technological change, resource scarcity and population dynamics in a Schumpeterian model with endogenous fertility. We find a pseudo-Malthusian equilibrium in which population is constant and determined by resource scarcity while income grows exponentially. If labor and resources are substitutes in production, income and fertility dynamics are self-balancing and the pseudo-Malthusian equilibrium is the global attractor of the system. If labor and resources are complements, income and fertility dynamics are self-reinforcing and drive the economy towards either demographic explosion or collapse. Introducing a minimum resource requirement per capita, we obtain constant population even under complementarity.
Book: pp. 130-137.
"Growth on a Finite Planet: Resources, Technology, and Population in the Long Run"
Economic Research Initiatives at Duke (ERID) Working Paper No. 147
Economic Research Initiatives at Duke (ERID) Working Paper No. 147
PIETRO F. PERETTO, Duke University - Department of Economics
Email: PERETTO@ECON.DUKE.EDU
SIMONE VALENTE, NTNU
Email: simone.valente@svt.ntnu.no
Email: PERETTO@ECON.DUKE.EDU
SIMONE VALENTE, NTNU
Email: simone.valente@svt.ntnu.no
Book: pp. 130-137.
Saturday, June 1, 2013
Tuesday, May 21, 2013
Lisbon Book Launch
The Lisbon book launch of Earth Economics will focus on fragmentation which is one of the major drivers of the political context that gives rise to new forms of economic diplomacy.
May 23, 1800
Instituto Superior de Ciências Sociais e Políticas
Rua Almerindo Lessa - 1300-663, Lisboa
Sala 3, Piso 3
Peter Bergeijk é Professor Catedrático em Economia Internacional e Macroeconomia no International Institute of Social Studies, Universidade Erasmus de Roterdão. No passado, foi Chief Trade Economist no Ministério Negócios Estrangeiros Holandês, entre outros cargos no sector privado, público e na academia. Entre as suas publicações mais recentes destacam-se Economic Diplomacy and the Geography of International Trade (Edward Elgar, 2009), The gravity model in international trade (Cambridge University Press, 2010; co-eds.), The Economic Effectiveness of Diplomatic Representation (The Hague Journal of Diplomacy, 2011) e Economic diplomacy, trade and developing countries (Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society, 2011), ou Earth Economics (Edward Elgar, 2013).
Sunday, May 5, 2013
Lenin could be wrong
"It is therefore impossible to conceive a capitalist nation without foreign trade, nor is there any such nation" - Vladimir Ilyich Lenin The DEVELOPMENT of CAPITALISM in RUSSIA, Chapter I. The Theoretical Mistakes of the Narodnik Economists, VIII. Why Does the Capitalist Nation Need a Foreign Market?
Wednesday, May 1, 2013
IMF's optimism
Forecasts for 2012 GPP growth adjusted in 11 editions of the World Economic Outlook (April 2008-April 2013) |
Book: Text Box 1.2, p. 6.
Thursday, April 25, 2013
Sunday, March 31, 2013
Eartheconomics: An alternative introduction
This paper sets out the didactical and logical arguments for using the closed economy concept at the start of introductory courses to discuss our planet’s economy. The paper illustrates how
observations at the level of planet Earth can be used while teaching
relationships that are studied in a closed economy setting. It provides an
overview of internet resources with world data and some practical examples that
can readily be used in teaching.
Book: pp. 1-8, 11-18 (updated tables), 71-72 (exercise 6.5) and 126-128 (exercise 10.7)
Book: pp. 1-8, 11-18 (updated tables), 71-72 (exercise 6.5) and 126-128 (exercise 10.7)
Friday, March 29, 2013
Global Public Goods Supply and Conditional Transfers
"Improving
Global Public Goods Supply through Conditional Transfers - The International
Adaptation Transfer Riddle"
CESifo Working Paper Series No. 4106
CESifo Working Paper Series No. 4106
KAREN PITTEL, CESifo (Center for
Economic Studies and Ifo Institute for Economic Research) - Ifo Institute for
Economic Research
DIRK T. G. RÜBBELKE, Basque Centre for Climate Change (BC3), Basque Government - Basque Foundation for Science (IKERBASQUE)
DIRK T. G. RÜBBELKE, Basque Centre for Climate Change (BC3), Basque Government - Basque Foundation for Science (IKERBASQUE)
In
order to overcome the underprovision of global public goods various different
policy approaches have been proposed. In the climate policy arena,
international transfers are frequently seen as an effective means to raise the
provision of the global public good ‘climate change mitigation’. This paper
focuses on a specific type of international transfer that aims at raising
mitigation while also reducing the damages from climate change: conditional
adaptation support. Especially since the COP in Copenhagen 2009, preparations
are on-going to significantly expand international transfers that help
developing countries to adapt to climate change. While there are extensive
discussions in the policy arena about the required amount of adaptation funding
and the best ways to raise, manage and disburse these funds, hardly any
attention is paid to the international allocative effects of these transfers.
The answer to the question of ‘why’ international adaptation transfers are paid
at all, is often relegated to fairness considerations only. As adaptation
benefits are largely local and adaptation transfers reduce the recipients’
incentives to contribute to climate change mitigation, one would, however,
expect at least unease in donor countries about plans to significantly expand
international adaptation support. In this study, we compare two alternative
conditional transfer schemes: one plainly subsidizes mitigation efforts, while
the other provides adaptation support which is conditional on other agents’
mitigation contributions. Disregarding distributional and fairness aspects the
paper evaluates and compares the allocative effects of either policy scheme. It
is shown that while both policy schemes can be beneficial for developing as
well as industrialized countries, this outcome relies strongly on the
productivity of mitigation and adaptation technologies.
Book: pp. 149-160.
Book: pp. 149-160.
Monday, March 18, 2013
Planet Earth is Wage-Led!
Özlem Onaran takes us through an analysis of the effect of a decline in the wage share in GDP. The author asserts that when wage moderation and austerity measures are being formulated, it is important to realise that wages not only affect costs on one side but also affect demand on the other. According to Onaran through its effect on aggregate demand, a wage-led recovery is economically feasible as a way out of the global recession.
Book: p. 61 and 106.
Tuesday, March 12, 2013
A set back for globalization
The KOF globalization index released in March 2013 shows the impact of the Great Recession. Before 2008 there was a steady increase, but the index for 2009 and 2010 show that that progress halted.
Book: Section 13.1, pp. 152-3.
Other reading: On the Brink of Deglobalization: An alternative perspective on the world trade collapse.
See also this video
Sunday, March 10, 2013
Educating civil servants pays
Using the CVs of 131,877 of civil servants from 178 countries who applied to the IMF for training between 1981 and 2011, Rabah Arezki and Marc Quintyn("Degrees of Development" in Finance & Development, March 2013, Vol. 50, No. 1) are able to show that the better the level of education of a country's civil servants the better a country’s economic performance. Development is education; education is development.
Book: Exercise 10.3, p. 122.
Book: Exercise 10.3, p. 122.
World oil demand and supply
A recent OECD study of the world oil market investigates price and volume changes up till the year 2020. The study does not estimate a truly global demand function but works on the basis of regional aggregates. The graph below derived from Fournier, J. et al. (2013), “The Price of Oil – Will it Start Rising Again?”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers, No. 1031, OECD Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/5k49q186vxnp-en shows the impact of the 2008/9 crisis and assumes that world growth after being a broadly stable 2011-2012 will recover.
While the growth trajectory has a small confidence interval the oil price predictions are less accurate and depend on risk premium and the elasticities of income and price. The price development over the simulation period could be almost stable to a treefold increase.
The price path also illustrates nicely the pre-crisis sharp increase due to (perceived) scarcity and the impact of the crisis.
Book: Sections 3.3 pp. 33-34 and 12.3, pp. 144-146.
While the growth trajectory has a small confidence interval the oil price predictions are less accurate and depend on risk premium and the elasticities of income and price. The price development over the simulation period could be almost stable to a treefold increase.
The price path also illustrates nicely the pre-crisis sharp increase due to (perceived) scarcity and the impact of the crisis.
Book: Sections 3.3 pp. 33-34 and 12.3, pp. 144-146.
Two tales of global financial governance
Peter van Bergeijk gave a presentation at the annual conference of the AIV, the Dutch advisory council in international security. His presentation dealt with the public good aspect of international economic governance and with the often forgotten plight of the Least Developed Countries
Wednesday, March 6, 2013
Earth economics. Because it’s the only one we’ve got
Take a look
at the World Development Report or
the World Economic Outlook. It will be difficult to find anything on the
Earth economy in these flagship publications: the World Bank and the IMF
analyse world issues by aggregating nations into regions and regions into even
larger entities. Starting at the nation state, they expect to arrive at the the
world economy, but it is more probable that they actually lose sight of the
whole. What can you tell about beehives
if you study only the bees? That’s why there is an increasing demand for a new,
truly global approach.
The reason
to study Earth on its own is because Earth is a closed economy. Earth
cannot lend or borrow. Neither can Earth export or import. Earth will thus have
to resort to its own natural resources, its own factors of production, its own
saving and investment. Indeed, Earth cannot rely on others to provide raw
materials, labour, knowledge or capital. The message is clear: if you want to
understand Earth you have to study the planet as a stand-alone.
It is not simply
interesting to use this perspective. It is also the only logical approach and it
is a challenging line to attack economic processes. Eartheconomists
study short-term fluctuations and long-run growth in the Earth economy. They
use this highly aggregated level of analysis because the world economy is the
only economy where the concept of a closed economy – one that does not trade
with other economies – makes perfect sense. After
all Earth does not trade (yet) with Moon or Mars.
Of course this
does not mean that there is no international trade on Earth. The countries of
our globalized world trade with each other. The point is simply that our
world does not trade with other worlds and in this sense it is and remains a
closed economy.
The Earth
perspective provides a different and stimulating viewpoint than the usual analyses
based on the aggregate findings for the individual countries in the world
economy. This is because the Earth perspective shows the big picture and asks
nagging questions:
·
What
would be the best course of action for a world government?
·
How
can we increase Earth’s human, natural and physical capital?
·
How
to distribute Earths proceeds? (and to whom?)
·
How
could we improve the well-being of all earthlings?
·
How
can we ensure that the earthling –
now and in the future – develops, learns, gets work, produces…?
Many object
to the analysis of Earth as a closed economic system. They say that the
simplicity of the closed economy is unrealistic in view of the complexity of
the real world. It is true that eartheconomics
‘neglects’ that countries can learn from, cooperate with and help each
other, but also that countries differ to a large extent, focus on national
interests and may not agree on the appropriateness of some considered economic,
monetary and/or financial policy. These costs should not be neglected,
but they should also not be exaggerated and – importantly – be balanced against
the benefits of a new manner of framing policy questions that are
important for world development.
Down to Earth
Eartheconomics is no l’art pour l’art. The questions that eartheconomists
study are relevant because economic policies influence large numbers of
people around the globe in a very concrete way: unemployment, growth and
inflation influence our daily lives. The important issues are to understand:
- the causes and consequences of short-run fluctuations (the business cycle),
- the determinants of long-run economic growth (increases in national income) and the long economic waves, and
- what we can and, equally importantly, cannot do to stimulate development and prevent or remedy downturns of the economy.
Answering the last
question (what we can and cannot do) always requires a close examination of actual
economic variables, their development and relations with other economic
variables. This is why Earth Economics
is as much about theory and empirical research as it is
about policy. This book respects the heritages of Keynes (short-term
demand management: the ISLM model) and Solow (long-run neoclassical growth). I
do so not out of economic respect, but because these tools are very useful to
understand the Great Recession and also because they are in a down to earth
manner elementary to analyse the policy responses to that crisis.
Global public goods (and bads)
Earth’s
economy cannot flourish without global public goods, such as human health care,
the environment, universal education and peace. Likewise global public bads are
a threat to Earth’s economy: pandemics, climate change, financial instability
and widespread poverty are clear examples. Global public goods include global rules
and regulations that are highly important for the proper functioning of
the Earth economy. Examples are the rules against economic discrimination
provided by the World Trade Organization, the labour standards provided by the
International Labour Organization and the health and food safety requirements
set by the World Health Organization and the Food and Agriculture Organization.
The Security Council of the United Nations sets political norms and values
backed up by economic sanctions and peace-keeping missions. These forms of
governance are important facilitators if not drivers for global economic
cooperation and the global division of labour. Eartheconomists therefore study the
developments of the economic conditions for the provision of global public
goods. This also provides the basis for understanding the prospects for policy
coordination and multilateral rules and regulations.
Obviously,
it is from an economic theoretic point of view important to realize that we can
and actually should use the closed economy model to teach and understand eartheconomic
developments: unlike many economists think, closed economy models do not only serve
a didactic purpose, but actually make sense empirically. This is a nice point,
but that is not the only reason to become an eartheconomist. Eartheconomics frames the major issues in
(economic) policy in a context that goes beyond nations, nationalities and
nationalism.
Friday, March 1, 2013
How to make appropriate comparisons over time?
Question: the World Development Indicators (WDI) do not provide constant price numbers for: (i) bilateral aid flows, (ii) FDI and (iii) remittances. These variables are
only available in current US$. is there a way to convert current to constant so
that I can analyze the data over time
There are three strategies that you can follow.
The first strategy is to express these variables in terms of nominal GDP for which the WDI provides the current US$ values. This will not give you constant price numbers of course but it will provide you with a number that is not influenced by inflation as both the numerator and the denominator are influenced in the same way by inflation. The proper interpretation of a series in per cent of GDP is that it reflects the importance of the flow for the economy. (If the economy grows and all else remains equal the ratio of flow to GDP decreases).
The second strategy is to divide the series in current US$ by an appropriate deflator (index number). Here you have to chose an appropriate indicator, for example, the US Consumer Price Index and the US GDP deflator. You can get the US CPI from the WDI (current base year 2005 = 100). (The US GDP deflator could be used in the same way; the WDI provides annual percentage changes - so the inflation rates - that you should use to calculate the indexnumbers). Deviding the current US$ values by the index numbers will provide you with a constant price series in 2005 US prices. This corrects for US inflation but in some cases that may not be what you need.
The third strategy is to express the series in another currency and then use the appropriate price index number related to that country. For example if you want to know how much goods and services could be bought by the foreign finance flow to which the question refers in the recipient country the you should use the local currency unit. This recipe requires two steps
Book: Section 3.2 pp. 29-33.
There are three strategies that you can follow.
The first strategy is to express these variables in terms of nominal GDP for which the WDI provides the current US$ values. This will not give you constant price numbers of course but it will provide you with a number that is not influenced by inflation as both the numerator and the denominator are influenced in the same way by inflation. The proper interpretation of a series in per cent of GDP is that it reflects the importance of the flow for the economy. (If the economy grows and all else remains equal the ratio of flow to GDP decreases).
The second strategy is to divide the series in current US$ by an appropriate deflator (index number). Here you have to chose an appropriate indicator, for example, the US Consumer Price Index and the US GDP deflator. You can get the US CPI from the WDI (current base year 2005 = 100). (The US GDP deflator could be used in the same way; the WDI provides annual percentage changes - so the inflation rates - that you should use to calculate the indexnumbers). Deviding the current US$ values by the index numbers will provide you with a constant price series in 2005 US prices. This corrects for US inflation but in some cases that may not be what you need.
The third strategy is to express the series in another currency and then use the appropriate price index number related to that country. For example if you want to know how much goods and services could be bought by the foreign finance flow to which the question refers in the recipient country the you should use the local currency unit. This recipe requires two steps
- Use the WDI DEC alternative conversion factor LCU per US$ (The DEC alternative conversion factor is the underlying annual exchange rate used for the World Bank Atlas method. As a rule, it is the official exchange rate reported in the IMF's International Financial Statistics (line rf). Exceptions arise where further refinements are made by World Bank staff. It is expressed in local currency units per U.S. dollar.)
- Divide the LCU value by the country CPI index (the base year will differ by country)
Book: Section 3.2 pp. 29-33.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)